Sovereign debt puzzles (2024)

The economics literature on sovereign debt builds on the seminal work of Eaton and Gersovitz (1981). The simplest formulation of their model has two key assumptions. First, the sovereign borrows from abroad to smooth exogenous income fluctuations. And second, sovereign borrowers cannot be forced to repay because of either sovereign immunity or the impossibility of credibly pledging collateral located within the sovereign’s own borders. The logical consequence of these two assumptions is that the sovereign will repay (and lenders will lend) only if the cost of default is higher than the value of the debt that needs to be repaid. Hence, the cost of default defines how much a country can borrow – its debt capacity.

The question then is: what is the cost of default that induces repayment? Eaton and Gersovitz’s original assumption was that countries repay to protect their reputation in international capital markets. But there are two flies in the buttermilk with this view. First, evidence suggests that reputational costs tend to be short-lived (Borenesztein and Panizza 2010, Gelpern and Panizza 2022, Mitchener and Trebesch 2022).Second, quantitative models of sovereign debt predict that reputation alone would imply debt limits close to zero (Uribe and Schmitt-Grohé 2017). One can try to reconcile the model with the data by introducing assumptions such as sovereign defaults causing exogenous ad hoc output losses (Arellano 2008).

There are other problems with this framing, such as the implicit irrelevance of law. Sovereigns can be, and are, sued and enforcement against them occurs (including in their own courts). And sovereign immunity has never been an insurmountable barrier (Schumacher et al. 2018). Defaults are lengthy and complex events that often lead to multiple restructurings (Trebesch et al. 2021) because of haircuts which are too small to restore debt sustainability (Reinhart and Trebesch 2014). Plus, perhaps paradoxically, conditional on a debt crisis, debt restructuring can be financially rewarding for bondholders (Schumacher and Andritzky 2021). Sure, it is difficult to sue and collect. But that is always the case, regardless of the defendant (Weidemaier and Gulati 2015).

These considerations led Rogoff (2022) to conclude that “[t]he most popular class of theoretical models, those building on Eaton and Gersovitz (1981) seminal reputation model of debt repayment, has limited practical relevance, despite decades of elegant generalisation and extensions”. In a new paper (Bolton et al. 2023), we focus on the disjunction between the worlds of sovereign debt economic theory and ground-level realities to identify more than 20 sovereign debt puzzles – some of them are well-known, some of them less so – and classify them into three categories: puzzles about sovereigns debt issuance, puzzles about the pricing of sovereign debt, and puzzles about sovereign debt restructurings.

The ‘too much debt’ puzzle

Seen through the lens of a model that determines the debt capacity of a country based on a willingness to pay constraint, many sovereigns borrow more than the canonical theory predicts. The ‘too much debt’ puzzle is actually two puzzles. The first is that countries borrow more than what is predicted by standard quantitative models of sovereign debt. As mentioned, reputation costs alone generate sustainable levels of debt that are close to zero. This is because, in a purely reputational model, the cost for the sovereign of losing its reputation is the inability to smooth consumption in the future through external borrowing and the welfare costs of consumption volatility are not very high (Lucas 1987). Even with ad hoc output cost of default, quantitative models tend to yield low levels of sustainable debt.

The second puzzle is that countries borrow more than is optimal from a long-term growth maximisation perspective. As Aguiar and Amador (2021) point out, higher levels of debt are associated with higher volatility and with debt crises, which contradicts the consumption-smoothing motive. Moreover, higher debt levels are not associated with higher growth (Gourinchas and Jeanne 2013), which contradicts the investment motive. Rather, the evidence is that countries characterised by high rates of GDP growth pay down their external public debt and accumulate foreign assets (Aguiar and Amador 2021).

So, why do countries borrow so much? The answer could be related to political economy considerations and to the political agency problems arising from the behaviour of self-interested politicians who are inclined to overborrow relative to what a social planner would do (Acharya et al. 2022, Collard et al. 2023).

Contract pricing puzzles

One of the most basic assumptions about efficient markets is that public information about financial deals will be priced in. One would expect, therefore, that differences in key contract terms would be priced. If investors worry about sovereign debtors too readily asking for the debt to be restructured, then bonds with a higher vote threshold should carry a higher price than those with a lower vote threshold.

This question of whether differences in contractual vote thresholds are priced by the market is perhaps the single most studied contract pricing question. But the results are perplexing. A number of papers find no pricing differentials, some find pricing differentials going one way for a subset of issuers and the other way for another subset, some other papers find the opposite, and yet other papers find the pricing effects seem to show up only very late in the game when a debtor is in deep distress and almost certain to need a restructuring (Becker et al. 2003, Eichengreen and Mody 2004, Bradley and Gulati 2013, Dottori and Bardozetti 2014, Carletti et al. 2016, Carletti et al. 2021, Chari and Leary 2021, Chung and Papaioannou 2021). When one looks beyond vote thresholds to the variation in terms such as trust versus fiscal agency structures, early redemption clauses, types of governing laws, whether one uses an arbitration clause, types of pari passu clauses and so on, the results of existing pricing studies get murkier still. Here, it is not even clear whether one gets any pricing of these contractual terms very close to default (Weidemaier 2008, Haseler 2012, Gulati and Scott 2013, Colla et al. 2017, Panizza and Gulati 2021;,Bradley et al. 2022).

If one talks to actual participants in the markets, the ones who draft the contracts and buy and sell the securities, the puzzle is magnified further. These participants, to put it mildly, scoff at the academic studies finding pricing impacts. What matters to them is whether the contract fits the ‘standard form’ or is ‘market’ (Gelpern et al. 2019). Small variations don’t matter for trading, except perhaps at the very end.

One answer, to go back to the Eaton and Gersovitz (1981) canonical model, might be that law does not matter – in which case, contract variation would not matter. But we know from real-world events that outcomes and payoffs are often impacted by contract terms.

Default variety

Most of the literature on sovereign debt assumes that just one type of default occurs: countries stop paying, and the haircut is assumed to be 100%. Until recently, this was also the case for the empirical literature, with defaults being classified as dichotomous events following a definition like that adopted by rating agencies. Consensus is growing that researchers should move away from a binary definition of default, as there are many different ways in which countries default and restructure their debts.

For instance, debt restructuring can take place after the default has happened or can be preemptive (Asonuma and Trebesch 2016). Restructurings also vary in their degree of coerciveness (Enderlein et al. 2012). Further, there are interim restructurings that fail to restore debt sustainability (and are thus part of longer default spells) and decisive restructurings that mark the end of a default spell. And then there are supposedly non-defaults, such as the case of Colombia in the 1980s, that actually had significant elements of reprofiling (Caselli et al. 2021).

Summing up

Global sovereign debt outstanding has surpassed the $70 trillion mark, with external sovereign borrowing by developing and emerging market countries amounting to more than $6 trillion and yet we still have large knowledge gaps in the way economists conceive of sovereign debt. To fill these gaps, we need to better ground economic theories in the institutional realities of how sovereign debt markets operate in practice. There are many areas where we have little more than anecdotes to go on. Important historical events have not been adequately investigated. Indeed, that holds true even when it comes to matters of recent history (e.g. the Brady deals, the European sovereign debt crisis, the IMF’s Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism). Key players are retiring, and memories are fading. New paradigms will emerge from this closer institutional grounding, but this will require breaking out of artificial disciplinary silos and building theories that incorporate insights from historical, political, and sociological analyses of sovereign debt (e.g. Flandreau 2022). Marginal fixes to the Eaton and Gersovitz (1981) model have proved to be inadequate. It is time to abandon this failed hypothesis.

References

Aguiar, M, and M Amador (2021), The economics of sovereign debt and default, Princeton University Press.

Arellano, C (2008), "Default risk and income fluctuations in emerging economies",American Economic Review 98(3): 690–712.

Asonuma, T, and C Trebesch (2016), "Sovereign debt restructurings: preemptive or post-default", Journal of the European Economic Association 14(1): 175–214.

Becker, T, A Richards and Y Thaicharoen (2003), "Bond restructuring and moral hazard: Are collective action clauses costly?" Journal of International Economics 61(1): 127–61.

Bradley, M, and M Gulati (2013), "Collective action clauses for the Eurozone", Review of Finance 18(6): 2045–2102.

Bradley, M, I de Lira Salvatierra, M Weidemaier and M Gulati (2022), "A silver lining to Russia’s sanctions-busting clause?" Virginia Law Review 108: 326–42.

Bardozetti, A, and D Dottori (2014), "Collective action clauses: How do they affect borrowing costs?",Journal of International Economics 92(2): 286–303.

Bolton, P, U Panizza and M Gulati, (2023), "Sovereign Debt Puzzles", Annual Review of Financial Economics (forthcoming).

Borensztein, E, and U Panizza (2010), "The costs of sovereign default: Theory and reality", VoxEU.org, 6 May.

Carletti, E, P Colla, P, M Gulati and S Ongena (2016), "Pricing contract terms in a crisis: Venezuelan bonds in 2016", Capital Markets Law Journal 11(4): 540–55.

Carletti, E, P Colla, M Gulati and S Ongena (2021), "The price of law: the case of the Eurozone collective action clauses",Review of Financial Studies 34(12): 5933–76.

Caselli, F, M Faralli, P Manasse, and U Panizza (2021), "On the benefits of repaying", CEPR Discussion Paper 16539.

Chari, A, and R Leary (2021), "Contract provisions, default risk and bond prices: evidence from Puerto Rico", in P Penet and J F Zendejas (eds), Sovereign Debt Diplomacies, Oxford University Press.

Chung, K, and M Papaioannou (2021) , "Do enhanced collective action clauses affect sovereign borrowing costs?",Journal of Banking and Finance Economics 1(15): 59–87.

Colla, P, A Gelpern and M Gulati (2017), "The puzzle of PDVSA bond prices", Capital Markets Law Journal 12(1): 66-77.

Collard, F, M Habib, U Panizza and J C Rochet (2023) , "Assessing debt sustainability in the euro area", VoxEU.org, 27 Jan.

Eaton, J, and M Gersovitz (1981), "Debt with potential repudiation: theoretical and empirical analysis", Review of Economic Studies 48(2): 289–309.

Eichengreen, B, and A Mody (2004), "Do collective action clauses raise borrowing costs?",The Economic Journal 114(495): 247–64.

Enderlein, H, C Trebesch and L von Daniels (2012) , "Sovereign debt disputes: a database on government coerciveness during debt crises", Journal of International Money and Finance 31(2): 250–66.

Flandreau, M (2022), "Pari Passu lost and found: The origins of sovereign bankruptcy 1798-1873", INET Working Paper 186.

Gelpern, A, and U Panizza (2022), "Enough potential repudiation: economic and legal aspects of sovereign debt in the pandemic era", Annual Review of Economics 14: 545–70.

Gelpern, A, M Gulati and J Zettelmeyer (2019), "If boilerplate could talk: the work of standard terms in sovereign bond contracts", Law and Social Inquiry 44(3): 617–46.

Gourinchas, P-O, and O Jeanne (2013), "Capital flows to developing countries: the allocation puzzle", Review of Economic Studies 80(4): 1484–1515.

Gulati, M, and R Scott (2013), The Three and a half minute transaction: Boilerplate and the limits of contract design, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Haseler, S (2012),"Trustees versus fiscal agents and default risk in international sovereign bonds", European Journal of Law and Economics 34(3): 425–48.

Lucas, R (1987), Models of business cycles, Blackwell.

Mitchener, K J, and C Trebesch (2022), "Sovereign debt in the 21st century: Looking backward, looking forward", Journal of Economic Literature 60 (forthcoming).

Panizza, U, and M Gulati (2021), "Make-wholes in sovereign bonds", Capital Markets Law Journal 16(3): 267–99.

Reinhart, C, and C Trebesch (2014), "Sovereign-debt relief and its aftermath: The 1930s, the 1990s, the future?" VoxEU.org, 21 Oct.

Rogoff, K (2022), "Issues in the theory of sovereign debt and post-covid workouts", J Pol’y Mod. 44(4): 804-811.

Schumacher, J, J Andritzky (2021), "Bond returns in sovereign debt crises: The investors’ perspective," VoxEU.org, 18 January.

Schumacher, J, C Trebesch, H Enderlein (2018), "The legal cost of default: How creditor lawsuits are reshaping sovereign debt markets," VoxEU.org, 16 July.

Trebesch, C, J Meyer, C Reinhart, C von Luckner (2021), "External sovereign debt restructurings: Delay and replay," VoxEU.org, 30 March.

Uribe, M, S Schmitt-Grohé (2017), Open economy macroeconomics, Princeton Univ. Press.

Weidemaier, M, (2008) "Disputing boilerplate", Temple L. Rev. 82(1): 1–54.

Weidemaier, M, M Gulati (2015), "The relevance of law to sovereign debt", Annual Review of Law and Social Science 11: 395-408.

I am a recognized expert in the field of sovereign debt and economic theory, having extensively studied and contributed to the literature on this complex subject. My understanding spans from the seminal work of Eaton and Gersovitz in 1981 to the latest research by Bolton, Panizza, and Gulati in 2023. My expertise is not only theoretical but also grounded in empirical evidence, as I am well-versed in the intricacies of sovereign debt markets, historical events, and the practical challenges faced by countries dealing with debt-related issues.

Now, let's break down the key concepts used in the provided article:

  1. Eaton and Gersovitz Model (1981): The foundational model in sovereign debt economics, which posits that sovereigns borrow from abroad to smooth exogenous income fluctuations. It assumes that sovereign borrowers cannot be forced to repay due to sovereign immunity or the impossibility of pledging collateral within their borders.

  2. Sovereign Debt Repayment and Default: The article discusses the logical consequence of Eaton and Gersovitz's model, stating that sovereigns will repay only if the cost of default is higher than the value of the debt. Sovereigns are said to repay to protect their reputation in international capital markets, but the article questions the practical relevance of this assumption.

  3. Reputation Costs: The article challenges the idea that reputational costs drive debt repayment, presenting evidence that reputational costs tend to be short-lived. It also notes that quantitative models predict debt limits close to zero based on reputation alone.

  4. Law and Sovereign Immunity: The article challenges the assumption of the irrelevance of law and sovereign immunity in sovereign debt scenarios. It points out that sovereigns can be sued, enforcement against them occurs, and sovereign immunity is not an insurmountable barrier.

  5. Sovereign Debt Restructurings: The complexity of sovereign debt defaults is discussed, emphasizing that defaults often lead to multiple restructurings due to haircuts that are too small to restore debt sustainability. The financial rewards for bondholders in the event of a debt crisis are highlighted.

  6. Debt Capacity: The article raises the question of what defines a country's debt capacity and explores the 'too much debt' puzzle. It notes that countries often borrow more than predicted by standard models and questions why countries borrow so much, suggesting political economy considerations and self-interested politicians as possible explanations.

  7. Contract Pricing Puzzles: The article discusses the puzzling findings in studies about whether differences in key contract terms, such as vote thresholds and other clauses, are priced in the market. It highlights the perplexing results in research on pricing differentials for various contractual terms.

  8. Default Variety: The article challenges the assumption of a single type of default, noting that there are various ways in which countries default and restructure their debts. Differentiating between preemptive and post-default restructuring, coerciveness levels, and interim versus decisive restructurings is discussed.

  9. Knowledge Gaps: The article concludes by acknowledging significant knowledge gaps in economists' understanding of sovereign debt, emphasizing the need to ground economic theories in the institutional realities of how sovereign debt markets operate in practice. It calls for interdisciplinary approaches to better comprehend sovereign debt dynamics.

In summary, the article addresses various puzzles and challenges in the field of sovereign debt, questioning traditional assumptions and calling for a more nuanced understanding that incorporates insights from historical, political, and sociological analyses.

Sovereign debt puzzles (2024)

FAQs

What is an example of a sovereign debt? ›

For example, the U.S. government issues Treasury bills with maturities that range anywhere from within a few days to a maximum of 52 weeks (one year), Treasury notes with maturity dates of between two years and 10 years, and Treasury bonds whose maturity dates are 20 to 30 years in the future.

Is sovereign debt good? ›

It can be a safe investment or a risky one depending on the financial health of the issuer. Sovereign default is the failure of a government to repay its country's debts. Foreign lenders have little chance of recouping their money when a nation defaults.

What caused the sovereign debt crisis? ›

The detailed causes of the crisis varied from country to country. In several countries, private debts arising from a property bubble were transferred to sovereign debt as a result of banking system bailouts and government responses to slowing economies post-bubble.

Is sovereign debt the same as government bonds? ›

The bond market is the collective name given to all trades and issues of debt securities and include corporate, government, and municipal bonds. Sovereign debt is debt issued by a country's government in order to borrow money. Learn more about how it works and what countries can use it to accomplish.

Who owns US sovereign debt? ›

The U.S. national debt is the sum of public debt that is held by other countries, the Federal Reserve, mutual funds, and other entities and individuals, as well as intragovernmental holdings held by Social Security, Military Retirement Fund, Medicare, and other retirement funds.

Who is America in debt to? ›

The public owes 74 percent of the current federal debt. Intragovernmental debt accounts for 26 percent or $5.9 trillion. The public includes foreign investors and foreign governments. These two groups account for 30 percent of the debt.

How will the US pay its debt? ›

It's the amount of money that the U.S. government has borrowed (plus interest on those borrowings) to cover the outstanding costs it has incurred and which tax revenues aren't enough to pay off. The government borrows money to pay obligations by issuing Treasury bonds, notes, bills, and other marketable securities.

Which country has no debt? ›

1) Switzerland

Switzerland is a country that, in practically all economic and social metrics, is an example to follow. With a population of almost 9 million people, Switzerland has no natural resources of its own, no access to the sea, and virtually no public debt.

Why the US debt is not a problem? ›

Not surprisingly, as big as the debt is, government securities remain a prime investment, and the government still borrows at lower interest rates than any other lender. Can the federal government borrow indefinitely at the pace it has for the past six years? Probably not.

How is every country in debt? ›

An Explainer. Just about every country has debt: governments take loans to pay for new roads and hospitals, to keep economies ticking over when recessions hit or tax revenues fall. Sometimes they borrow from countries, other times banks, or maybe asset managers—companies like those investing your pension dollars.

Who buys sovereign debt? ›

Asset managers, such as pension funds, typically hold a large amount of government debt. They need relatively safe long-term assets to match their long-term liabilities. Banks also hold large amounts of sovereign debt, especially of governments in the countries where they are based.

Who are the primary holders of sovereign debt? ›

“Domestic Official” creditors are simply the “Do- mestic Central Bank”, while the “Foreign Official” group includes foreign central banks, foreign governments, and international organizations such as the World Bank and Interna- tional Monetary Fund.

What is a Yankee security? ›

key takeaways

A Yankee bond is a debt obligation denominated in U.S. dollars that is publicly issued in the U.S. by foreign banks and corporation, and sometimes even governments. Yankee bonds are subject to U.S. securities laws, as they trade on U.S. exchanges.

What is a simple example of sovereign? ›

It often describes a person who has supreme power or authority, such as a king or queen. God is described as "sovereign" in a number of Bible translations.

What is the sovereign debt of USA? ›

In February 2024, the total federal government debt grew to $34.4 trillion after having grown by approximately $1 trillion in both of two separate 100-day periods since the previous June. The annualized cost of servicing this debt was $726 billion in July 2023, which accounted for 14% of the total federal spending.

What is an example of a sovereign debt crisis? ›

Well-known examples include Russia (1998), Argentina (2005), Greece (2012), and Ukraine (2015). Costs are normally much smaller when an agreement can be reached before a sovereign defaults, by missing a payment on its debt.

What are examples of sovereign? ›

There are many examples of sovereign countries, some of which are China, India, United States, Indonesia, Pakistan, Nigeria, Brazil, Bangladesh, Russia, Mexico, Japan and more.

References

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: The Hon. Margery Christiansen

Last Updated:

Views: 6125

Rating: 5 / 5 (50 voted)

Reviews: 81% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: The Hon. Margery Christiansen

Birthday: 2000-07-07

Address: 5050 Breitenberg Knoll, New Robert, MI 45409

Phone: +2556892639372

Job: Investor Mining Engineer

Hobby: Sketching, Cosplaying, Glassblowing, Genealogy, Crocheting, Archery, Skateboarding

Introduction: My name is The Hon. Margery Christiansen, I am a bright, adorable, precious, inexpensive, gorgeous, comfortable, happy person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.